email

View Comments

Mud People and Super Farmers

BOOK EXCERPT from Hotel Africa: The Politics of Escape

By G. Pascal Zachary | October 3, 2013

CREDIT: Adam Cohn (CC).

In contrast with peasants in Asia and Latin America, few in Africa are landless. In rural Africa, land is plentiful, population densities are low by global standards, peasants continue to stream into cities, and plantations—or large aggregations of land for the purposes of farming—are rare (outside of southern Africa and Kenya, where plantations might otherwise be exceptional had they not been assembled during periods of foreign rule as part of unsustainable approaches to commercial agriculture).

Thus, land reform, in the African context, does not neatly fit the familiar meanings derived from the mass struggles arising from the Asian or Latin American experience. (For vivid evidence of this perspective, read Che's diary of his 1960s Congo sojourn.) In Africa, finding ways to use land productively—and to protect land sustainably—remains an elusive project, and partly because of the grave errors notched by imposing onto African peasants "lessons" from elsewhere in the world, where conditions differ dramatically.

One of those inappropriate lessons is the outsized emphasis on the value of explicit legal property rights (a position trumpeted by the Brazilian economist Hernando de Soto and, thus, derived from the Latin American landscape). In Africa, where land is relatively plentiful, the instrument of property rights appears to be a solution looking for a problem—an alien instrument imported by outsiders largely ignorant of the rural reality.

In the following example of land-use improvisation in East Africa, traditional self-reliance is fused with a newfound zeal for market-oriented tactics in ways that both highlight the value of a property-rights regime and suggest its short- and long-term costs.


In the lush highlands of eastern Uganda, mud is a valuable commodity—so long as it is "quality" mud, with certain characteristics coveted by residents who construct their homes out of the stuff.

The search for great mud is simple. Go north toward the town of Sironko about ten miles from the provincial capital of Mbale and then, a few hundred feet past a tall cellular phone tower, you turn off the paved road and wind down a potholed lane. There you join a procession of mud customers. They come in trucks, cars, and even on bicycles. Upon reaching the village, Bukhalo, drivers turn left onto a narrower path that takes them into the finest mud quarry for many miles.

About two dozen families control specific pieces of the mud quarry. Each hires their own diggers, sells their own mud, and sets prices independent of each other. No individuals possess formal, legal title to their portion of the mud quarry, but no one considers this strange. Claims on the mud lands stretch back to the years before Uganda's independence in 1962, when the British managed these parts. Everyone knows that their ancestors bequeathed them the use of a particular patch of the mud quarry. No one has ever asked for proof of their ownership, or even tallied the costs of forgoing title in favor of "customary law."

Yet costs are clear. The two dozen families are mired in mistrust. Intra-family squabbles dominate conflicts. Theft of mud, often at night, is common. Without clear boundaries between mud plots, no one seems responsible for insuring the quarry is flushed with adequate levels of water. No improvements to the quarry have been made. There's no marketing of the mud. The quarry even lacks a sign.

Disputes between conflicting mud entrepreneurs do get settled, but often by visits from the police or trips to the local judge. Settlements are idiosyncratic. And no one keeps records of anything, so when the same type of dispute surfaces, the whole issue must be handled anew.

Worse, the lack of cooperation, borne of mistrust and unspecified property rights, produces a "beggar thy neighbor" approach to the pricing of mud. A truck load of mud can fetch $50 on a good day. Yet on any given day, buyers of mud flock to the person selling for lower prices; and that's usually the seller with the most urgent need for cash. Rather than create a mud cartel—and set a common price and literally "carve up" the market in an orderly manner—owners undercut each other in a race that some days leads to the bottom. The process hurts everyone in the village by reducing its prized asset.

The trials of Bukhalo's mud people suggest an urgent need for new legal and political arrangements. In eastern Uganda, as in much of rural sub-Saharan African, land titles don't exist. There is no national movement in Uganda to get land titling either. Not even experimental titling projects exist. And customary ownership arrangements, stretching back hundreds of years, seem destined to exist for an eternity, despite their painful costs.

On the bright side, I've made seven visits to Bukhalo since 2005 and I've learned that the missed opportunities for the mud quarry, however perplexing, coexist with a growing appreciation among Bukhalo's farmers for the benefits of property rights.

Farmers in these parts grow food for themselves, but they also grow a variety of cash crops: corn, cotton, beans, peanuts, and sunflower seeds. Corn is especially profitable because it stores well and can be sold across borders. Buyers in Kenya and south Sudan, both within easy reach, pay more than the local market—sometimes double.

The appetite for corn has ignited a frenzy among the enterprising farmers for more land. The more land they farm, the more corn they can grow (and cash they can "harvest"). The obstacle to greater wealth, however, is the same as that faced by the mud harvesters: no property rights, no titles, no open market for the buying and selling of land, and no use of land as collateral against loans.

For decades farmers accepted the situation. Much land, as a consequence, sat idle. When a family left for the big city—as many have done—their land lay fallow. Families often refused to allow others to farm it, fearing that by doing so, even in return for "rent," they might lose their customary ownership of the land. Barter presented a solution but often crops could not easily be turned into cash, rendering them essentially valueless to an absentee farmer. So the safest path was to idle the land until a family returned to work it themselves.

When Ken Sakwa returned to his family land in Bukhalo from Kampala, the capital of Uganda, he faced this very situation. Having failed to earn a decent living in the big city, he took up farming on his late father's land about ten years ago. After six frustrating months in which he succeeded only in reminding himself how little he remembered about the intricacies of farming, Mr. Sakwa married a talented female farmer from a neighboring village.

Working as a team, Ken and Jessica Sakwa began an upward ascent. Within a few years, they were farming the three acres that Ken inherited. They started to save money. There is little to buy in Bukhalo and the Sakwas are thrifty. They kept their money hidden in their mud house until one day Mr. Sakwa had an idea: He knew the price of corn and he knew that many neighbors lacked the labor or enterprise to farm all of their land. Why not rent or buy the idle land from his neighbors?

Mr. Sakwa found a neighbor willing to sell him a suitable piece of land. To secure the deal, he wrote up a simple contract and the seller signed.

The contract, two pages long, boiled down to a single sentence: "I Madam Kawna have sold my swampy land of 61 strides in length and 32 strides in width for 330,000 shillings," or about $185.

Mr. Sakwa obtained a half-dozen plots of land in this same way over the course of a few years. He established a fair price by calculating how much corn the land can produce in a normal year. Then he subtracted his expected expenses and gave the seller a portion of the annual anticipated profits from farming the land.

The agreements have helped the Sakwa family prosper. But because there are no formal land titles, only idiosyncratic contracts filed with a local magistrate, disputes are common. Having paid in advance for use of a neighbor's land, Mr. Sakwa sometimes faces "submarine" claims by people who say they are relatives of the seller and insist they too should receive money for his use of "their" land.

Mr. Sakwa has successfully fended off these claims with the help of a local judge, who understands that, even in the absence of a land titling system, exchanges of land for money are occurring, and will continue to occur, in part because of the market incentives to farm idle land. This judge has helped Mr. Sakwa settle disputes, though in two cases he has been forced to make additional payments to the original owners.

Fear of legal wrangles discourages Mr. Sakwa from making more land deals. Rather than expand his holdings in an insecure fashion, he is shifting away from farming and moving into the buying and selling of crops. He bought a truck with money that might have gone into more land acquisitions. And with his truck, he began a thriving business buying crops from growers and then ferrying the crops to buyers in cities. While margins are relatively small, and Mr. Sakwa must sometimes front money to farmers for seeds or to help them in emergencies, he prefers his emergent role in agrobusiness over the tricky task of assembling more farm land.

CREDIT: CIAT/Neil Palmer (CC).

These very different tales in one African village present a common lesson for property-rights advocates. The attachment to customary land arrangements, coupled with the absence of a political movement to bring explicit property rights to rural Africans, means that the full benefits of legal land ownership will escape ordinary Africans for some time, perhaps many years. The ultimate answer is for government and civil society to mount a comprehensive campaign to title rural land in much the same way as they have done in most African cities, where urban land is backed by legal titles, registered with courts and government agencies. Notably this includes private residences.

The major obstacle to a broad-based political campaign for expanded land rights is the relatively weak position of rural people throughout the sub-Saharan. There are flickering signs of change. The African Union, the region's leading political association, raised the profile of land issues in 2009 with a "declaration" on "the need for strong systems of land governance." But there's been no agreement on what those systems should look like, and designing a one-size fits all approach seems unlikely.

In some highly centralized countries, such as Ethiopia, the government appears to want weak land rights in order to facilitate land "sales" to foreign agrobusiness companies. In countries with strong democratic traditions, such as Ghana, the power of land is so distributed and shared that making refinements to customary principles is difficult, if not impossible in rural areas where the need for new approaches is most urgent.

And then there are countries such as Kenya, South Africa, and Zimbabwe, where white settlers stole or appropriated prime land during colonial periods and where efforts at redress have been either stalled, abandoned, or mishandled. In these countries, "legacy" land issues overshadow the sorts of everyday practical reforms that are still needed.

In short, despite a growing awareness of the importance of improving "systems of land governance," land reform remains a low priority in Africa, especially in rural Africa, where most people still live and work as farmers.

Yet the experience of Bukhalo, Uganda is a source of optimism. While the need for titling and clearer property rights is clear in this one village, the lack of them is not paralyzing. The people of Bukhalo are not passively accepting their situation but rather they are fitfully improvising, crafting creative adaptations to difficult situations. These adaptations, as the choices of both the mud quarry owners and the Sakwa family suggest, are not without shortcomings, yet they deserve to be viewed as part of a journey toward true property rights—a bumpy but genuine one.

Read More: Agriculture, Business, Cities, Democracy, Development, Economy, Food, Governance, Jobs, Migration, Poverty, Ethiopia, Kenya, South Africa, Uganda, Zimbabwe, Africa

blog comments powered by Disqus

Site Search

Global Research Engine

This search includes our Core Network partners.

Join Our Mailing Lists

The Journal

varietal-attraction