View Comments

Time to Nationalize Insolvent Banks

By Nouriel Roubini | Project Syndicate | February 26, 2009

CREDIT: GetHiroshima (CC).

A year ago, I predicted that the losses of U.S. financial institutions would reach at least $1 trillion and possibly go as high as $2 trillion. At that time, the consensus among economists and policymakers was that these estimates were exaggerated, because it was believed that subprime mortgage losses totaled only about $200 billion.

As I pointed out, with the United States and global economy sliding into a severe recession, bank losses would extend well beyond subprime mortgages to include subprime, near-prime, and prime mortgages; commercial real estate; credit cards, auto loans, and student loans; industrial and commercial loans; corporate bonds; sovereign bonds and state and local government bonds; and losses on all of the assets that securitized such loans. Indeed, since then, the write-downs by U.S. banks have already passed the $1 trillion mark (my floor estimate of losses), and institutions such as the IMF and Goldman Sachs now predict losses of more than $2 trillion.

But if you think that the $2 trillion figure is already huge, the latest estimates by my research consultancy RGE Monitor suggest that total losses on loans made by U.S. financial firms and the fall in the market value of the assets they hold (things like mortgage-backed securities) will peak at about $3.6 trillion.

U.S. banks and broker dealers are exposed to about half of this figure, or $1.8 trillion; the rest is borne by other financial institutions in the United States and abroad. The capital backing the banks' assets was only $1.4 trillion last fall, leaving the U.S. banking system some $400 billion in the hole, or close to zero even after the government and private-sector recapitalization of such banks.

Another $1.5 trillion is needed to bring banks' capital back to pre-crisis level, which is needed to resolve the credit crunch and restore lending to the private sector. So, the U.S. banking system is effectively insolvent in the aggregate; most of the British banking system looks insolvent, too, as do many continental European banks.

There are four basic approaches to cleaning up a banking system that is facing a systemic crisis: recapitalization of the banks, together with a purchase of their toxic assets by a government "bad bank"; recapitalization, together with government guarantees—after a first loss by the banks—of the toxic assets; private purchase of toxic assets with a government guarantee (the current U.S. government plan); and outright nationalization (or call it "government receivership" if you don't like the dirty N-word) of insolvent banks and their resale to the private sector after being cleaned.

Of the four options, the first three have serious flaws. In the "bad bank" model, the government may overpay for the bad assets, whose true value is uncertain. Even in the guarantee model there can be such implicit government over-payment (or an over-guarantee that is not properly priced by the fees that the government receives).

In the "bad bank" model, the government has the additional problem of managing all the bad assets that it purchased—a task for which it lacks expertise. And the very cumbersome U.S. Treasury proposal—which combines removing toxic assets from banks' balance sheets while providing government guarantees—was so non-transparent and complicated that the markets dove as soon as it was announced.

Thus, paradoxically nationalization may be a more market-friendly solution: it wipes out common and preferred shareholders of clearly insolvent institutions, and possibly unsecured creditors if the insolvency is too large, while providing a fair upside to the taxpayer. It can also resolve the problem of managing banks' bad assets by reselling most of assets and deposits—with a government guarantee—to new private shareholders after a clean-up of the bad assets (as in the resolution of the Indy Mac bank failure).

Nationalization also resolves the too-big-to-fail problem of banks that are systemically important, and that thus need to be rescued by the government at a high cost to taxpayers. Indeed, the problem has now grown larger, because the current approach has led weak banks to take over even weaker banks.

Merging zombie banks is like drunks trying to help each other stand up. JPMorgan's takeover of Bear Stearns and WaMu; Bank of America's takeover of Countrywide and Merrill Lynch; and Wells Fargo's takeover of Wachovia underscore the problem. With nationalization, the government can break up these financial monstrosities and sell them to private investors as smaller good banks.

Whereas Sweden adopted this approach successfully during its banking crisis in the early 1990s, the current U.S. and British approach may end up producing Japanese-style zombie banks—never properly restructured and perpetuating a credit freeze. Japan suffered a decade-long near-depression because of its failure to clean up the banks. The United States, the United Kingdom, and other economies risk a similar outcome—multi-year recession and price deflation—if they fail to act appropriately.

© 2009 Project Syndicate. Republished with kind permission.

Read More: Business, Debt, Economy, Finance, Governance, United States, Americas

blog comments powered by Disqus

Site Search

Global Research Engine

This search includes our Core Network partners.

Join Our Mailing Lists

The Journal